Famous quotes

"Happiness can be defined, in part at least, as the fruit of the desire and ability to sacrifice what we want now for what we want eventually" - Stephen Covey

Sunday, January 15, 2012

AMAZING GAME THEORY post by Presh Talwalkar


How Game Theory Solved a Religious Mystery

Talmud
image source: marvinxsteadfast via flickr
The Bankruptcy Problem
A man owes debts of 100, 200, and 300, but dies with insufficient funds to pay everyone.
How should his estate be divided?
As we all know, there might not be one correct answer. Fair division is a concept that depends as much on logic as it does on social custom. To see why, consider the following three situations that afford very different solutions:
  • A parent promises gifts to his children, but has to back off when a bonus is smaller than expected
  • A publicly traded company issues stock and bonds, but soon goes bankrupt in an accounting scandal
  • Partygoers order items at a restaurant, with promises to pay, and then end up arguing over the best way to split the bill
There isn’t a single right way to approach any of these problems. That’s what family fights, lawsuits, and restaurant arguments demonstrate every day. The conflict is a matter of perspective.
Some people prefer proportional division that depends on debt size. An example is the classic “pay what you ordered” method in restaurants where guests put money based on food they ordered. As logical as this sounds, not everyone desires this method.
Others prefer splitting things up equally. They argue it is the person–not the debt size–that matters. Equal division is common particularly among families with young children. During Christmas or holiday time, parents may choose to give every child the same gift regardless of age or merit.
What gets accepted depends on social custom. Getting everyone to agree is an exercise in persuasion, not in economics. It’s possible for emotionally pleasing methods to beat more sound systems (like my time-tested method for dividing bills fairly in large groups).
One of the earliest discussions of fair division comes from the Babylonian Talmud, a record of discussions about Jewish laws and customs. The Talmud contains discusses a bankruptcy problem in the context of a man offering debts to his wives in excess of his assets. The Talmud answer is not immediately obvious, and in fact, the answer baffled academics for over almost 2,000 years. Let’s see why.
The Talmud answer
How should an estate be divided among three creditors claiming sums of 100, 200, and 300?
The Talmud offers answers through three examples. The text does not contain a general rule, which is what makes these answers seemingly contradictory. The three cases are when the estate size is 100, 200, and 300.
In the first case when the estate size is 100, the Talmud awards 33 1/3 to each party. The division suggests a principle of an equal division, which is easy mathematically and holds social appeal. But strangely this is not the same idea used in the other cases.
In the third case of 300, the Talmud offers a division of 50, 100, and 150. The math here is a proportional division based on the size of the debt. In modern times, proportional division holds wide appeal among lawyers and economics. At this point one might ask why is the 300 case treated differently than the 100 case?
If that question bothers you, then get ready for another surprise in the division for 200. In this case, the estate is supposed to be divided as 50, 75, and 75. Not only does the division not classify as an equal division nor a proportional division, but it is simply a curious decision altogether. Why should the second and third creditors be given the same amount of money? And where do the numbers come from?
Before I proceed, it’s worth summarizing the claims in a table. We can think about the Talmud answers as a table that illustrates how an estate would be divided. I provide an illustration below, in which the rows are estate sizes, the columns are claims, and the table entries are the division size.
Talmud division game theory bankruptcy problem
The answers defied a proper explanation for almost 2,000 years, filling volumes of critical review. Some scholars have essentially given up and suggested the 200 case might be an issue of faulty transcription. And this is the unlikely background for which game theory enters and possibly saves the day.
Game theory offers an answer
In the 1980s, Professors Robert Aumann and Michael Maschler wrote a paper claiming to have cracked the mystery.
They suggest there is no inconsistency in the Talmud answer. Aumann and Maschler demonstrate the Talmud answer can be viewed as a consistent application of a game theory principle. Why was game theory used? It turns out the Talmud answer is the solution (the nucleolus) of a properly defined coalitional game. Aumann and Maschler explain the concept in lay terms as a single and consistent principle: equal division of the contested sum.
It is worth being skeptical before proceeding. Is the explanation simply a coincidence? After all, there are probably an infinite number of explanations that might produce the same split.
Aumann and Maschler justify their answer by examining other Talmudic passages and suggesting the same principle is applied in many topics. Equal division of the contested sum was apparently a social custom and that would help explain why it might seem strange to us but could have been natural for their culture.
Below I explain the concept of “equal division of the contested sum,” and describe why the Talmud answer demonstrates it.
(Notes for the sources: The original academic paper is in Journal of Economic Theory 36 (1985), pp. 195-213 (full paper). For this article, I relied on a complementary non-technical article “Game Theory in the Talmud,” written by Robert Aumann, retrieved from Professor Jacob Rosenberg’s website. I also wish to credit Paul Walker’s chronology of game theory, the document that introduced me to this fascinating problem).
Equal division of contested sum, two people
The Talmud examines a situation that might have been common to their times. Suppose two people are arguing over a garment. One claims half belongs to him while the other claims the whole is his. A judge is asked to decide who gets what. What would you do?
There are naturally various answers. One could propose an even split (1/2, 1/2) or a proportional split (1/3, 2/3).
But the Talmud offers a different answer, an answer that turns out to be an equal division of the contested sum (1/4, 3/4). How does this principle work? There are three stages. First, decide what portion of the cloth is being disputed. In this case, exactly half of the garment is being claimed by both parties. Second, split the disputed division among both parties–so 1/4 of the cloth is awarded to each. And third, give the remaining cloth–the “undisputed” portion–entirely to the person whose claim is not disputed.
This logic yields a split of 1/4 for the person claiming half of the garment and 3/4 for the person claiming the whole.
Talmud contested garment
This answer might seem strange, but remember that division methods depend on social custom.
The same method can be used for any problem among two parties, using the same three steps above:
  1. Determine which portion is contested or claimed by both parties
  2. Split the contested portion equally
  3. Assign the uncontested portion to the sole person claiming it
How else might this principle be applied? It can actually be applied to many situations, like when the claims are larger than the asset to be divided, as in the case of dividing an estate.
Equal division of contested sum, two creditors
It’s worth going through a few examples to get a feel for the idea. Let’s examine how to divide estates of various sizes with two creditors claiming 100 and 300.
Example 1: (estate 66 2/3)
If the estate is 66 2/3, then the entire estate is contested. The split should be even at 33 1/3 going to each party.
Example 2: (estate 125)
If the estate is 125, then the first 100 is contested by both parties and divided evenly. The remaining 25 is entirely awarded to the 300-claimant. Hence, the division is 50 and 75.
Example 3: (estate 200)
Finally, if the estate is 200, then again the first 100 is contested by both parties and divided evenly. The remaining 100 is entirely awarded to the 300-claimant. Hence, the division is 50 and 150.
Here are the divisions in tabular form:
Talmud division game theory bankruptcy problem 100 300
Why stop there? Here are some examples when the claims are (100, 200) and (200, 300). Note that these are the remaining pairs of claims for the three-person split that is motivating this article.
Talmud division game theory bankruptcy problem 100 200 Talmud division game theory bankruptcy problem 200 300
Explaining the Talmud puzzle
Let’s go back to the Talmud division for the three creditors. In the case of a 200 estate, the division was 50, 75, and 75 for parties that claimed debts of 100, 200, and 300.
To analyze this answer, let’s do the following exercise. Take any two creditors and consider how they might split the total money awarded to them. Why would we do that? It’s a check of consistency. It makes sense that pairs of creditors should have claims divided in a manner consistent with the way a disputed garment would be divided.
Consider the pair of creditors claiming 100 and 200. Together they are awarded a sum of 125. How is that sum split? It is split as 50 and 75. And amazingly, that’s matches the work we did in examples above: this answer is consistent with an equal division of the contested sum! The logic is that the first 100 is contested by both parties and split evenly, and the uncontested 25 is awarded to the 200-claimant.
In fact, the same observation can be seen when considering other pairs of creditors. Look at how much the 100 and 300 parties are getting. Together they receive a sum of 125, and this is split as 50 and 75. Again, this answer is consistent with an equal division of the contested sum.
Finally, consider the total reward to the 200 and 300 parties. In this case, the total sum of 150 is split as 75 to each. As the total sum is contested, this once again reflects an equal division of the contested sum.
In other words, when the mysterious Talmud solution is broken down by pairs of creditors, there is a consistent principle. I think this is quite remarkable.
Aumann and Maschler demonstrate the method can be extended, whether the claims are for three creditors, a hundred creditors, or even a million creditors. The same condition needs to be met: the assets are divided up such that the amount received by any two people reflects the principle of equal division of the contested sum. Furthermore, the division is a unique solution.
An algorithm
It’s good enough to see certain divisions are pairwise equal divisions of contested sums. But how do you find them starting from scratch?
Aumann and Maschler show there is in fact only one division that is consistent. And this answer can be described by the following seven step algorithm:
  1. Order the creditors from lowest to highest claims.
  2. Divide the estate equally among all parties until the lowest creditor receives one half of the claim.
  3. Divide the estate equally among all parties except the lowest creditor until the next lowest creditor receives one half of the claim.
  4. Proceed until each creditor has reached one-half of the original claim.
  5. Now, work in reverse. Start giving the highest-claim money from the estate until the loss, the difference between the claim and the award, equals the loss for the next highest creditor.
  6. Then divide the estate equally among the highest creditors until the loss of the highest creditors equals the loss of the next highest.
  7. Continue until all money has been awarded.
Here is how the claims would be divided in the Talmud example:
Talmud division various assets
Mystery solved? I think so. Not only do the Talmud answers follow a consistent principle, but they also rely on an idea that was very likely a social custom.
In that case, it is surely an interesting case that a tool of logic and rationality–game theory–was needed to decode the Talmud solution, which primarily depended on social custom.

Friday, January 13, 2012

Wonderful post by Rajeev srinivasan on Indian History

Commentary/Rajeev Srinivasan


The Battle of Colachel: In remembrance of things past

A dramatic and virtually unknown past, in an area of bucolic calm surrounded by spectacular hills: that is Colachel, a name that should be better known to us. For this is where, in 1741, an extraordinary event took place -- the Battle of Colachel. For the first, and perhaps the only time in Indian history, an Indian kingdom defeated a European naval force.
The ruler of Travancore, Marthanda Varma, routed an invading Dutch fleet; the Dutch commander, Delannoy, joined the Travancore army and served for decades; the Dutch never recovered from this debacle and were never again a colonial threat to India.
It was a remarkable achievement for a small princely state; yet not one of my Indian friends has ever heard of the Battle of Colachel. This, in my opinion, is another example of our sadly skewed education -- we have adopted wholesale a Macaulayite curriculum that was designed to drum into Indians the notion that we were inherently inferior, mere powerless pawns in a European-dominated world.
We study events where Indians were crushed, massacred, trounced, humiliated: Plassey, Panipat, Tarain, Chittor, the failed First War of Independence, Jallianwallah Bagh. We study about every invader, from Alexander the Macedonian onwards, who came over the Himalayan passes and laid waste to the land. We study the disastrous history of the Indo-Gangetic Plain.
We never hear of the far more lustrous history of the Peninsula -- not of Rajendra Chola's maritime Southeast Asian empire, nor the wealth and power of fabled Vijayanagar, nor the chivalrous chaver suicide squads in the Zamorin's kingdom at Kozhikode, nor even about perhaps the greatest of Indian philosophers, the Buddhist Nagarjuna. This is a serious lacuna --and yet we wonder why we as a nation suffer from an inferiority complex?
Colachel is on the route from Thiruvananthapuram to Kanyakumari, which has some dramatic shifts of scenery. You drive down the ill-named National Highway 47, in reality an overcrowded two-lane road with no centre divider, no more than a city street with a continuous population along its entire length.
A typical interior Kerala landscape surrounds you -- tropical abundance, coconut palms, rice fields, plenty of greenery, banyan, jackfruit, tamarind and mango trees, and houses within a stone's throw of the road. Then you cross into Tamil Nadu's Kanyakumari district, and you pass my personal landmark, a century-old aqueduct.
Suddenly, without warning, the landscape opens up -- you come upon an immense flood-plain, with paddy fields, lotus-filled pools, a small river, and occasional clumps of banana trees stretching all the way to the horizon. Except, that is, where the hills are -- the very last redoubts of the Western Ghats, as the land yields grudgingly to the oceans at the Cape: A series of jagged and menacing peaks towering over you.
One especially well-shaped, conical mount resembles, in its symmetry, the Grand Tetons of Wyoming; but otherwise, the forbidding, brooding peaks of granite remind you of rogue elephants. Nestled incongruously amongst these hills is Mahendragiri, where the Indian Space Research Organisation's rocket testing facility is located.
Close by is Colachel with its Round Fort. It has a strategic and commanding view of the Arabian Sea; on a clear day you can see as far south as Land's End, the promontory at Kanyakumari. It was here, with the tactical genius of Marthanda Varma's prime minister, Ramayyan Dalava, that the Dutch fleet was vanquished. I imagine infantrymen with ancient blunderbusses repelling invaders; and a battery of archaic cannon making mincemeat of the attacking ships. It was here that the Dutchman, Delannoy, later trained Travancore soldiers in the arts of musketry and artillery.
Delannoy lies entombed at an inland fort, Udayagiri, a few miles away from Colachel. At his tomb, there is an inscription: Stand, Traveller, and behold! For here lies Captain Delannoy, who served Maharaja Marthanda Varma and Travancore faithfully for three decades
This foreigner, this feringhee, served our country well, two hundred years ago. How little we know of the reasons this man agreed to serve an enemy prince. It could hardly have been coercion -- not if he stayed on for the rest of his life. It must have been a genuine respect for, and perhaps admiration and even affection for this land and this prince.
It behooves us to understand that even at the height of the European colonisation spree, there were Indians capable of resisting and winning. Most of us know that in 1905, the Japanese under Admiral Tojo trounced the Russians in the Yellow Sea. This is considered the first example of an Asian power defeating a European power in a naval engagement. Yet here we have little Travancore defeating the Dutch two-and-a-half centuries ago; the same Dutch who went on to conquer and dominate the entire Indonesian archipelago.
As the saying goes, those who forget their history are condemned to repeat it. History is one of the most precious possessions of a people; the other being their common culture. Somehow, a common Indian culture has emerged over several millennia; nevertheless, we have been distressingly lax about remembering our past.
Perhaps because we have so much history, it has become meaningless for us. But the only way we can build up a common purpose is through the use of common mythologies and a shared racial memory. Based on our experiences, it can be argued that an open economy and free trade would be disastrous for us. There is genuine concern that the rapine and pillage of the transnational corporation will be as bad as the excesses of our former colonists. The spectre of the East India Company continues to haunt us; so do Union Carbide and Bhopal.
Behind that fear is the implicit assumption that our people and our institutions are somehow weak; somehow unable to withstand the onslaughts of rapacious aliens. Yet, as Colachel shows, there was at least one occasion when we could and did stand up to the European marauder. Our lack of faith in our ability to be competitive is at least in part because we study only a history of defeat.
Furthermore, there were great trading centers in the Peninsula -- troves of ancient Roman, Greek, and Phoenician coins have been found at Bharuch in Gujarat, Kodungalloor (Muziris) in Kerala, and Arayikkamedu in Tamil Nadu. Peninsular India was the center of a thriving and lucrative trade in gems, spices, silk, and other luxuries, much of it trans-shipped from further east such as the Moluccas or China. Ancient and medieval Indians were no mean traders; if we can recapture some of that entrepreneurial spirit -- and it is certainly alive in overseas Indian populations -- we have little to be afraid of. There is no obstacle in our path that we cannot overcome.
As we rush headlong into globalisation -- as Octavio Paz, the Mexican poet, once said of his own country, we also seem 'condemned to modernise' -- it behooves us to look into our past. For, in the cyclical nature of the Hindu universe, it is suggested that what once was, will be once again. We need to look at the Colachels of our past; not only the Jallianwalla Baghs.
Rajeev Srinivasan

Monday, January 02, 2012

Why this Kolaveri Di - Top song of the year 2011

Incredible this is the Top song of the year. Amazing !!! it got released only in November 2011 and it has already gone absolutely nuts.... CNN report below

The fall of Dallas Mavericks

It was really sad to watch the Dallas Mavericks fall to a 1-4 start to a truncated season of NBA.At this rate the Dallas might have to struggle just to make the playoffs with Clippers,Timberwolves and Warriors looking like a far better side than the one that played in the previous season.The main factors that could contribute to the downfall are the following......
Insane deal to let go Tyson Chandler and JJ Barea
How in the world the Mavs thought that the only focal point of their defense of a championship team is not worthy of an extended.Come on Mark Cuban cant you offer more than a year for Tyson Chandler,thats ridiculous the guy helps you get your first ring and then you treat him like a disposable commodity,thats not fair.Looking at the Knicks this year Tyson might be the missing puzzle that the knicks are waiting for.

What does JJ Barea have to do to get an extended deal.He was the only reason why Mavs won that crucial game in the Finals when Dirk fell sick and JJ Barea scored a valuable 20 odd points running circles around the Miami defense.The very fact his current side Timberwolves defeated the Mavs yesterday is sweet justice for him.




Not to mention the trade of Caron Butler who is one their consistent performers.
 
The Replacements

What has the Dallas Mavericks got in return. Lets see that they did receive two All Stars in the form of Vince Carter and Lamar Odom. But both of them are in the fag end of their careers and are probably not starter material but still effective.Vince Carter - the most entertaining player to have ever played the game but rarely has a side ever won a playoff series because of him.He cannot carry sides to victory, the best he can do is to play a support cast to Dirk and score some points and looking at the way he is playing he simply cant dunk anymore either.Lamar Odom looks disoriented in the Dallas team.He probably needs more time to fine tune his setup plays with his team members.It takes time even for veterans to gel like a team and this Nba Lockout has ensured that they have no time whatsoever. With the hectic schedule it is more likely Dallas goes from bad to worse.

The Hopefuls

There might be a chance that Dallas can come back and thats through their marquee player Dirk Nowitzki. He usually heats up at the fag end of the season and lets accept it ...there is absolutely no defense against the Dirk fade away. The veterans Lamar,Kidd and Carter might bring in their experience in crunch games and they can very well cause problems for any defense in the playoff games.But Vince and Dirk has no defensive skills at all.There is also the fact that Beaubois is back and healthy. He is probably their only hope now...



He is probably the smoothest player in the NBA and the only player other than Dirk to have ever scored more than 50 points in a game for the Mavericks.How come he is not a starter is beyond me.......

As of now it looks like Dallas is not even trying for a repeat.